Democracy and the Economy: The Cost of Non-Democracy

Foto: Imago

Populism is on the rise. What does that mean not only for the state of our liberal societies but also for the economy? Is economic growth thinkable under non-democ­ratic rule? Joost Haddinga explores the inter­change of the two. He is awarded first prize for his contri­bution to our essay compe­tition organized by WirtschaftsWoche and Center for Liberal Modernity.

How do the economy and democracy go together? According to standard eco- nomic theory the answer is simple: Inclusive insti­tu­tions, and democracy in the form of the rule of law and central government together with limited power of politi­cians pave the road towards economic prosperity in the long-run and permit societies to break out of their growth-preventing shackles of the past.

Non-democ­ratic economic prosperity: A mere pipe-dream?

Despite this, the demand for more author­i­tarian govern­ments or populist leaders, however, has not subsided in western societies. Either due to genuine appeal of their solutions and simple answers, or sheer dissat­is­faction with estab­lished parties, more people have turned to populists in the West in recent years. In recent elections, nation­alist and populist leaders across Europe have regained power, such as Giorgia Meloni in Italy in 2022, during the 2024 European elections, the near-win of the National Rally in the French parlia­mentary election in July 2024, while especially in Eastern Germany the ”Alter­native for Deutschland” (AfD) remains a signif­icant force. The question thus arises which case, if any, can be made for non-democ­ratic economic prosperity. Is it a pipe dream or real alter­native to the past, in which sustainable long-run growth was only achieved by liberal democracies?

Lessons from history

The first question is what the historical record shows for populists and au- thori­tarian leaders. Recent research by Moritz Schularick, Manuel Funke, and Christoph Trebesch strongly suggests that populist leaders damage economic pros- perity and inhibit progress rather than accel­er­ating it. Further, the question is less whether they can achieve higher growth rates but more whether they can sustain prosperity for a long time and prevent episodes of shrinking. Economies grow mainly because they stop shrinking and experi­encing fewer crises (instead of growing quicker in calm periods) and for the past 200 years only developed democ­racies have sustained such a pathway even though also dicta­torship experi­enced temporary growth spurts.

But dictators and populists can create prosperity if they adhere to fruitful policies and work on replacing themselves by a set of more inclusive insti­tu­tions — especially for countries with a weak insti­tu­tional framework. To remain prosperous for long, however, all evidence points towards only democ­racies being able achieve this. Daron Acemoglu and James Robin- son have popularised the conno­tation that only a suffi­ciently strong and inclusive insti­tu­tional framework guided by a strong civil society leads to long-run pros- perity. If either is too strong or too weak, no long-run economic growth will be observed.

Non-democ­ratic economic growth relies on exploitation

Non-democ­racies, while capable of catch-up growth, rely on extractive and exploitative growth. Once all sources of exploitation have been tapped, the economy stagnates and no further prosperity is observed. This phenomenon was what plagued the Soviet Union which first observed mirac­ulous growth rates in the 1920s and 1930s, but stagnated for most of the postwar period. One may view this similarly as a medium-income trap: for non-democ­racies it is possible to attain levels of prosperity that guarantee basic needs for their citizens. With growing income, however, also the expec­ta­tions and standards of people grow, especially in terms of what personal liberties they require. As a non-democracy cannot guarantee them, the only way towards more prosperity lies in a democ­ratic transition, unless new sources of exploitation are discovered. Acemoglu et al. further back this argument by studying the impact of democracy on growth, showing that democ­ratic turns boost GDP per capita by about 20 percent in the long run. Consistent with the research by Funke, Schularick, and Trebesch non-democ­ratic turns are therefore not conducive to economy.

Who benefits?

The second question is whether non-democ­ratic govern­ments raise the welfare of their citizens (i.e. by deficit spending in the present and large transfers while sacri­ficing future prosperity) or whether only particular groups benefit from their rule. Even though populist leaders like to portray themselves as saviours of the ordinary citizenry, the evidence on them raising economic welfare is rather scant. A forceful historical case comes from the Third Reich. Despite Hitler being known for his large spending on transport infra­structure and labour programs to alleviate unemployment, he was not an advocate of Keynesian economics. First, most of his spending was geared towards the military, and second he was careful not to extend the German government budgets too much, hence cutting in other places such as social spending. Even though his highway-building programmes are often cited collo­quially, there is no evidence to see Hitler as being preoc­cupied with the welfare of the German population beyond nourishing a capable army as increases in public spending were devoted to the military almost exclu­sively. Though elites and people 3
rhetoric strongly empha­sised the positive welfare conse­quences of national socialism, the general population did not experience substantial increases in per capita incomes.

Taking a look at Russia and China

More contem­po­ra­neous views are offered by Russia, that experi­enced democ­ratic back- sliding after 2012, and China. Russia’s GDP per capita declined by more than a third between 2013 and 2016 following its gradual inter­na­tional isolation and has not really recovered since. The Chinese experience of stable though during the 2010s slowing economic growth, sustained since the country’s entrance onto the inter­na­tional stage under Deng Xiaoping in the 1980s seems to be the radical oppo- site and a role model of non-democ­ratic growth. Still, this has to be approached with caution as the treatment of minorities and regime-critical people remains alarming, and the surveil­lance infra­structure and social credit system installed by the Chinese Communist Party create strong pressure to not deviate from official lines. Similarly, even though China has surpassed the US as the largest economy worldwide, its per capita incomes remain much lower, highlighting that much of its power its derived from its sheer size instead of high prosperity and produc­tivity of the Chinese population overall. Prosperity and welfare enhancement in these societies is therefore limited and often constrained to conforming people and elites, leaving minorities and dissenters behind.

The dream of a benev­olent dictator

The third question is which economic, political and insti­tu­tional framework is actually fit for prolif­er­ating economic prosperity sustainably in the future. The desire for strong (author­i­tarian) leaders stems for a large part from the natural deficiencies of democracy. Democracy is inher­ently slow. Its majorital decision- making processed based around delib­er­ation and compromise is slow and subject to changing elected officials. As more people contend that elected govern­ments are incapable of dealing with pressing societal needs such as public infra­structure, wealth inequality or global challenges such as global warming, and simul­ta­ne­ously gains from global­i­sation are distributed unequally, the demand for simple and straight­forward answers has risen. The theory of the benev­olent dictator that maximises the welfare of their citizens exists since Plato and has played a formative role in macro­eco­nomic theory as well: Fully informed decision-makers with perfect foresight choose a policy rule that eventually maximises social welfare. While economic theorists are usually aware of the benev­olent dictator being a mere illus­tration of infea­sible ideals given limited and dispersed infor­mation, the idea reemerges still from time to time.

From Plato to Hayek’s “Consti­tution of Liberty”

These theories abstract from the corrupting elements of power and incen­tives of political leaders to use their privi­leges to benefit their interest groups instead of the entire population — which in the real world are readily present. Even if this were no problem, the problem of infor­ma­tional asymme­tries remains: Where Hayek, who would have turned 125 years old in 2024, defended liberal democracy and a decen­tralised market economy against the threat of total- itari­anism and socialism based the coordi­nating mechanism of prices in a market- based economy, the same quest arises in the 2020s where prominent econo­mists and politi­cians call for the central admin­is­tration of fighting climate change or other grand challenges.

Hayek further acknowl­edged the demand for authority in his Consti­tution of Liberty as a means of being relieved of pressure and respon­si­bility but declined its validity based on two grounds: First, govern­mental struc­tures not aiming at minimising coercion lead to infringe­ments of personal liberties that in the end decrease innovation as fewer (randomly occurring) oppor­tu­nities can be exploited. Second, no leader possesses the knowledge to foresee the necessary steps to promulgate economic growth and by constraining market forces they limit the growth oppor­tu­nities of the economy severely. Even if they have all scien­tific knowledge at their disposal, this cannot suffice to success­fully predict innovation or successful inter­vention in other areas.

Economic growth and well-being of citizens

A further question arises as whether the economic outcome should be defined as an advance in economic growth, or more holis­ti­cally as advances in compre­hensive well-being of citizens. While economies such as China have experi­enced a growth surge, gains in non-democ­ratic societies remain distributed unequally: elites and regime-uncritical people gain while minorities and groups invoking personal liberties that exhibit potential danger for the ruling elite are system­at­i­cally discrim­i­nated against. Thus when consid­ering the detri­mental effects on personal liberties, the track record of non-democ­racies elevating prosperity is even more scant. The belief that under a strong and non- democ­ratic government things would be better hence results from a pitfall that Federic Bastiat described already in the 1850s as ”that which is seen, and that which is unseen”14: people pay attention to the deficiencies of the current system and point to other systems that correct exactly these deficiencies, not realising that these new approaches create novel (though different) deficiencies, which may be even more grave. For the current debate this means while autoc­racies may be more fast-moving than democ­racies, they provide even more perverse incen­tives for elites to abuse their power, often lead to restric­tions in personal freedoms and human rights, and suppression of minorities or regime-critical discourses.

Democracy and economic prosperity are interlinked

Non-democracy and populism are enticing sins. In their proposals they showcase the apparent benefits without even alluding to the inevitable costs, whether they would fall on current or future gener­a­tions. The historical record shows, however, that only democracy is capable of stimu­lating long-run economic prosperity by not relying on exploitation and preserving personal liberties. Though it might seem appealing to go elsewhere and to rely on a strong leader to get things moving, this quest is misleading in the naive thought that such leaders would act perfectly benev­o­lently while knowing exactly how to solve any mounting problem and not abuse any of their privi­leges, let alone try to extend their privi­leges. Especially in indus­tri­alised countries people should be careful what they wish for, as populist or non-democ­ratic rule have rarely provided grounds for economic prosperity. In the end answers for economic growth lie in inclusive insti­tu­tions and states having both the capacity and democ­ratic control not to be too pervasive.

This year’s jury consisted of Ursula Weidenfeld (freelance journalist), Karen Horn (University of Erfurt), Jan-Jonathan Bock (Hertie Foundation), Dieter Schnaas (WirtschaftsWoche) and Ralf Fücks (Center for Liberal Modernity). This text has already been published in Wirtschaftswoche.

 

Textende

Hat Ihnen unser Beitrag gefallen? Dann spenden Sie doch einfach und bequem über unser Spendentool. Sie unter­stützen damit die publizis­tische Arbeit von LibMod.

Wir sind als gemein­nützig anerkannt, entsprechend sind Spenden steuerlich absetzbar. Für eine Spendenbescheinigung (nötig bei einem Betrag über 200 EUR), senden Sie Ihre Adress­daten bitte an finanzen@libmod.de

Verwandte Themen

Newsletter bestellen

Mit dem LibMod-Newsletter erhalten Sie regelmäßig Neuigkeiten zu unseren Themen in Ihr Postfach.

Mit unseren Daten­schutzbes­tim­mungen
erklären Sie sich einverstanden.